I Hate Dialysis Message Board
Welcome, Guest. Please login or register.
October 11, 2024, 11:25:05 PM

Login with username, password and session length
Search:     Advanced search
532606 Posts in 33561 Topics by 12678 Members
Latest Member: astrobridge
* Home Help Search Login Register
+  I Hate Dialysis Message Board
|-+  Dialysis Discussion
| |-+  Dialysis: News Articles
| | |-+  Kidneys For Sale
0 Members and 4 Guests are viewing this topic. « previous next »
Pages: [1] Go Down Print
Author Topic: Kidneys For Sale  (Read 1580 times)
okarol
Administrator
Member for Life
*****
Offline Offline

Gender: Female
Posts: 100933


Photo is Jenna - after Disneyland - 1988

WWW
« on: May 15, 2011, 11:56:36 PM »

Kidneys For Sale
Posted on May 11, 2011 by admin
By Peyton R. Miller (Harvard University, Class of 2012).  Mr. Miller is a government concentrator.  An alternative Tuesday contributor to the Harvard Crimson.

Most proposed changes to the healthcare system involve a tradeoff between costs and health outcomes. A potential exception to this rule would be a policy that increases kidney donation, which would allow substantial savings on dialysis therapy for patients with end-stage renal disease. The policy would also improve these patients’ quality of life and reduce the kidney shortage that causes black market organ trafficking. While it would be controversial, a regulated market in which living persons could accept monetary compensation for kidney donations may be the best way to boost transplants.

About half a million Americans are being treated for kidney failure, also known as end-stage renal disease. The average wait for a kidney transplant, which is usually the optimal treatment, is about five years, and those without access to a donated kidney receive expensive dialysis therapy. Dialysis patients experience deteriorating health and living conditions, and many die waiting for a transplant. While donations have increased modestly in the past few years, demand has surged thanks to success with transplantation as well as an aging population and higher rates of chronic disease that cause kidney failure.

Although the risks of organ donation cannot be dismissed, the mortality risk for live kidney donors has been estimated at 0.03 percent. The reason supply does not rise to meet demand has less to do with the consequences of surgery than with the fact that U.S. law prohibits individuals from being paid for their organs, meaning transplants are provided entirely by altruistic donors.

The shortage created by this policy has led to another problem: illegal organ trafficking.  Legally prohibited from paying American donors, dialysis patients have been known to seek paid transplants from desperately poor people in developing countries. Americans travel abroad for transplants, particularly to South America, and there are even reports of third world donors being brought to the United States. Under-the-table transplants take place in medically precarious circumstances and are facilitated by organ traffickers, who often take advantage of donors’ poverty and ignorance. Murder for organ extraction and outright organ theft are rare, but it is not uncommon for traffickers to fail to pay willing donors their promised amount or to mislead them about the nature of the procedure. While there have been no comprehensive evaluations of the magnitude of organ trafficking, the heinous nature of the crime as well as its potential for growth in light of the ever-growing demand for kidneys, demands that it be addressed.

What can be done about the kidney shortage? The limited supply of viable organs from deceased donors and comparatively low rates of successful cadaveric transplants suggest that boosting deceased organ donation is only a partial solution. Attempts to increase altruistic donations by living donors have had limited success. On the other hand, economists Gary S. Becker of the University of Chicago and Julio J. Elias of Stanford estimated in 2007 that a payment of about $15, 200 per living kidney donation would generate enough willing donors to eliminate the shortage. Monetary compensation has worked in Iran, which created a government-run donor payment system in 1988, and for the past twelve years has been the only country in the world without a kidney waiting list.

Compared to the average medical cost of transplantation, which Becker and Elias put at $160,000, donor compensation would amount to a small price increase. The move could even be a cost saver. Dr. Arthur J. Matas of the University of Minnesota estimates payments on the order of $100,000 could be made to donors and still be cost-neutral given the savings on dialysis therapy. Since treatment for end-stage renal disease is covered by Medicare, an increase in kidney transplants would go a long way toward mitigating the program’s unsustainable budget trajectory.

The obvious caveat is that the market would need to be closely regulated to prevent the kind of exploitation that occurs in developing countries. The government would need to ensure that donors are fully informed of the consequences of surgery and receive adequate compensation and post-operative care. Even with such protections, an organ market might still be subject to criticism of exploitation of poor and lower middle-class donors, as well as its “commodification” of the human body and possible social repercussions for paid donors. These are legitimate objections, but it is doubtful that they outweigh the relief for dialysis patients, reduced incentives for organ trafficking, and substantial cuts to healthcare costs that would accrue from monetary compensation.

To establish a functional kidney market, Congress needs to repeal the ban on compensation and establish a regulatory framework. In the meantime, states can at least reimburse donors for the expenses of surgery. In January 2004, Wisconsin created a state income tax deduction for costs incurred by living donors in terms of travel, lodging, and lost wages, and seven other states have since enacted similar legislation. Altering incentives at the state level may be the best way to build support for a broader system of monetary compensation for organ donors. With proper oversight, such a system could eliminate a tremendous amount of suffering and waste.

http://www.kidneytransplantblog.com/?p=105
Logged


Admin for IHateDialysis 2008 - 2014, retired.
Jenna is our daughter, bad bladder damaged her kidneys.
Was on in-center hemodialysis 2003-2007.
7 yr transplant lost due to rejection.
She did PD Sept. 2013 - July 2017
Found a swap living donor using social media, friends, family.
New kidney in a paired donation swap July 26, 2017.
Her story ---> https://www.facebook.com/WantedKidneyDonor
Please watch her video: http://youtu.be/D9ZuVJ_s80Y
Living Donors Rock! http://www.livingdonorsonline.org -
News video: http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=J-7KvgQDWpU
lola
Elite Member
*****
Offline Offline

Gender: Female
Posts: 2167


I can fly!!!

« Reply #1 on: May 16, 2011, 10:33:31 AM »

 :clap; :clap; FYI Dr Matas at the UofM is a JERK!!! But I do think giving someone some money is a good Idea and many more people would step up, many of the people who tested for Otto have jobs, and bills and being out of work would have been a HUGE burdden for them. just my :twocents;
Logged

lawphi
Full Member
***
Offline Offline

Gender: Female
Posts: 162


« Reply #2 on: May 16, 2011, 05:46:42 PM »

I wrote a law review article regarding donor compensation.  It wasn't publishable, but touched on the same facts and laws.  It is far cheaper to compensate a donor than the cost of a year of dialysis.  There is nothing funnier than watching a lawmaker with capitalist principals wither on living donor compensation. 

The current IRS guidelines will allow me to deduct every cent of hospital, travel and out of pocket medical expenses for my paired donation and what we spent for Hammett's surgery.  It won't be dollar for dollar, but I won't pay any income tax this year. 
Logged

Girl meets boy with transplant, falls in love and then micromanages her way through the transplant and dialysis industry. Three years, two transplant centers and one NxStage machine later, boy gets a kidney at Johns Hopkins through a paired exchange two months after evaluation.  Donated kidney in June and went back to work after ten days.
noahvale
Guest
« Reply #3 on: May 16, 2011, 06:12:00 PM »

*
« Last Edit: September 16, 2015, 08:53:40 AM by noahvale » Logged
Jie
Sr. Member
****
Offline Offline

Gender: Male
Posts: 521


« Reply #4 on: May 16, 2011, 11:05:01 PM »

I am not sure it can save money. With high mortality rates on dialysis, when a patient die, he or she is gone forever, and there is no more cost. With a low mortality rate from a living donor transplant, a patient can live longer and may use a lot more of resource over time. And when the transplanted kidney fails, she or he may need dialysis again, which may lead to more cost. This matter is similar to smoking. Smokers may use more healthcare money in a short term, but over a long term, a nonsmoker may cost more over her or his life time by living a lot longer.  I guess saving life is a better argument than saving cost.

Logged
Pages: [1] Go Up Print 
« previous next »
 

Powered by MySQL Powered by PHP SMF 2.0.17 | SMF © 2019, Simple Machines | Terms and Policies Valid XHTML 1.0! Valid CSS!